ブレトンウッズ体制の崩壊と不換紙幣の誕生

for the signing of the Bretonwoods Monetary 
Agreement authorized by President Truman to sign for the United States. Fiat currency, money backed 
by nothing but the threat of state violence. It’s valuable just because they say it is, but we know 
they’re going to just print and print until our savings turn to dust. Dust. This is of course as 
opposed to the good old days when money was backed by solid gold in a monetary system that everyone 
could believe in, right? Well, about that. Today, we investigate the system that came before fiat to 
find out how it worked, how it changed the world, and just how much better or worse it really 
was. My name is Guy, and you’re watching the Coin Bureau. Ah, New Hampshire. That charming 
little wedge between Maine and Vermont is home to Breton Woods, a picturesque resort community 
nestled in the White Mountains. Travelers flock to Breton Woods for its worldclass ski trails 
and breathtaking views. And on occasion, they’ve also convened at the Mount Washington 
Resort for 22 days of negotiations to establish a new international monetary order and found the 
International Monetary Fund and the precursor to the World Bank. Okay, that was just one occasion, 
but it was pretty important and not just for the locals. In July 1944, hundreds of delegates from 
44 allied nations gathered in Breton Woods for the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference, 
where they agreed to undertake a radical joint experiment in global monetary policy. In 
hindsight, though, their new system was doomed from the start, and it didn’t last all that long. 
But while it was in place, it profoundly changed the world, and its unceremonious ending in 1971 
has cast a long shadow over the global financial system ever since. Federal Reserve Chair Jerome 
Powell recently acknowledged as much in a speech to his colleagues at the Fed. He told them, quote, 
“The Bretonwoods agreement placed the US and the Fed in a central position in the global economy 
and its ending quote fundamentally changed the conduct of monetary policy as policymakers had 
to understand the effects of potentially more volatile movements of the US dollar.” So what 
exactly was agreed at Breton Woods and why? Well, the goal of the Bretonwoods Conference was to 
establish a stable and orderly international monetary system that would foster global trade 
and promote economic stability and prosperity after the Second World War concluded. You see, 
the international treaties that followed the end of the First World War had been an absolute mess. 
So bad, in fact, that they paved much of the road that led to World War II. So, the major powers 
and their allies were determined to get it right. this time and understandably placed a great 
emphasis on the need to replace chaos and conflict with stability and order. That all makes perfect 
sense. But as we’ll soon find out, the system that they agreed on at Breton Woods was fated to fail 
from the beginning. In hindsight, it’s kind of amazing how they overlooked the fatal flaw in its 
design. But since there were 730 delegates from 44 countries at the conference, well, let’s give them 
the benefit of the doubt. It’s not like they were a bunch of buffoons who just came for the skiing. 
To understand the agreement they came to, let’s first take a look at the road that led them to 
Breton Woods in the first place. So during World War I, the classic gold standard was suspended by 
the major powers who wanted to be able to print money to finance their war efforts. At the end 
of the war, some like France, Italy, and Great Britain tried to restore the gold standard in the 
1920s with limited success. One of the problems they faced was a lack of coordinated cooperation 
as central banks now distrusted one another’s currencies. As a result, they simply hoarded gold 
rather than recycling it through international credit. And this turned into a deflationary 
system. This all got a whole lot worse from 1929 as the Great Depression kicked off. In the 
early stages of the depression, post-war inflation was still fresh in the memory and central banks 
were reluctant to loosen monetary policy. Printing money was taboo as the lesson of the 1920s was 
that this led to currency collapse and loss of international confidence. As a result, some 
central banks were even raising interest rates as the economy was crumbling. To make matters worse, 
in 1930 the US introduced the Smoot Holy tariffs, starting a trade war that’s credited with cutting 
world trade by 2/3 in just 4 years. This turned out to be the final straw for central bankers 
who eventually caved and called it quits on the gold peg. The first domino fell in 1931 when the 
Bank of England abandoned the gold standard and devalued the pound by about 25%. This boosted its 
exports, but very much at the expense of everyone else who was still on the gold standard. They 
suddenly found their exports undercut by Britain and therefore uncompetitive, and they weren’t 
going to take that lying down. So, countries everywhere followed Britain’s lead, ditching the 
gold peg and devaluing their currencies to regain competitiveness. In reality, all of them were 
trying to export their own economic pain because this is a strategy of protecting your economy 
by throwing your neighbors under the bus. The result was a race to the bottom that destroyed 
all trust in the post-war international monetary arrangements and made the Great Depression 
considerably worse for everyone. Germany, Japan, and Italy increasingly turned to militarism 
while others formed currency blocks. The tensions in Europe led to significant capital flight to 
the US during the 1930s as despite the US economy being in the toilet like everywhere else’s. It 
was at least at arms length from warp prone Europe and its currency and markets appeared safe by 
comparison. Investors and even some central banks started converting assets into gold and shipping 
it to the US. The Federal Reserve Act of 1934 then turbocharged gold inflows in the US by raising the 
official price of gold from around $20 to $35 per troy ounce. This incentivized gold miners globally 
to expand production and for other countries and investors to sell their gold to the US at the new 
higher dollar price. As if that wasn’t enough, European rearmament also increased demand for US 
goods, leading to net merchandise exports from the US, which were often settled in gold. So this 
led to the US sitting on some 20,000 metric tons or 75% of the world’s gold reserves by 1944. Add 
to this the fact that Europe then blew itself to smitherines all over again in World War II and the 
small matter of the US leading the nuclear arms race and you have a recipe for post-war American 
hegemony. Apologies for the interruption folks, system was basically dictated by the United 
States and accepted by the other 43 countries at the conference. Although the Soviet Union ended 
up not joining the system because they recognized it as a tool of US economic hegemony. This suited 
the US just fine though because this meant there would be no one within this new global order who 
could challenge them. So what exactly was this system? Well, in a nutshell, Breton Woods was a 
model of international monetary policy that placed the US at the center of the economic universe and 
every other country in its orbit. If you’ve ever wondered why the dollar is the world’s dominant 
reserve currency, well, the short answer is Breton Woods. Under this system, the dollar’s global 
role was institutionalized by a new gold exchange standard. The dollar was pegged to gold at a fixed 
rate of $35 per troy ounce and the US government guaranteed the convertability of dollars into gold 
at this price for foreign governments and central banks. Meanwhile, every other country within the 
Bretonwood system pegged their currency to the US dollar at fixed parity rates. They were obliged 
to maintain these exchange rates with a narrow band of plus or minus 1% through intervention 
in foreign exchange markets. As such, buying and selling dollars to defend exchange rates became 
a major preoccupation of central banks, and this encouraged them to hold dollars in reserve. By 
1944, the US was the world’s largest economy, creditor, and exporter. And this meant that a lot 
of international trade ended up being settled in dollars. And since the dollar was as good as gold 
and a lot more practical to store and transport, it became the world’s primary reserve currency. 
and principal medium for international trade and investment. There was a big element of 
trust involved here though as countries had to believe that Washington was willing and 
able to honor its promise to convert any amount of dollars into gold at the request of central 
banks and foreign governments. To realize this new economic and financial order, the Bretonwoods 
Agreement created the International Monetary Fund and the International Bank for Reconstruction 
and Development, which later became part of the World Bank. The World Bank was established 
primarily to finance post-war reconstruction in Europe and promote economic development in member 
countries by providing loans for infrastructure and development projects, paid almost entirely 
in US dollars. Of course, the INF, meanwhile, was Bretonwoods’s cop on the beat. It was set up 
to monitor member count’s economic policies and exchange rates and ensure adherence to the 
fixed par system. Currency devaluations or revaluations exceeding 10% required IMF approval 
and were permissible only in cases of fundamental disequilibrium. And if you don’t know what that 
means, well, you’re not alone because it’s a term that was never formally defined and remains a 
mystery to this day. Meanwhile, another primary function of the IMF became to provide credit 
in US dollars to member countries experiencing temporary balance of payments difficulties, 
allowing them to correct imbalances without resorting to measures that the IMF disapproved 
of, like say currency devaluation. Now, these institutions were supposedly designed to 
promote stability and international cooperation, but they suffered from the perennial problem 
facing international governance bodies, enforcement. The IMF’s ability to compel policy 
changes was limited, especially in the US, which was not going to let anyone tell it 
what it could or couldn’t do. And since the US enjoyed the unique privilege of being able 
to issue the world’s reserve currency at will, perhaps you can see where this is all going. The 
Bretonwoods agreement and the IMF demanded that countries actively manage their exchange rates 
to maintain their pegs to the US dollar. However, the US, whose domestic, economic, and monetary 
policies had profound global implications, was not subject to the same degree of IMF discipline 
and didn’t actively manage its own exchange rate. As a result, the burden of adjustment to maintain 
the Bretonwoods system disproportionately fell on countries other than the US. And this lack of a 
robust mechanism to compel the reserve currency issuer to align its policies with global stability 
requirements was a critical flaw in the design and one of the reasons it wasn’t to last long. 
Meanwhile, the US didn’t make much of an effort to maintain the credibility of the dollar’s peg 
to gold and instead printed dollars like nobody’s business. This was due to among other things the 
massive expansion of the US military empire and its wars in Vietnam, Cambodia, Laos and elsewhere, 
as well as President Johnson’s Great Society policy program, all of which were very expensive. 
Wherever there was tension between the IMF’s mandate to maintain global monetary and fiscal 
discipline and the policy priorities of the US, the latter won out every time. And this did not 
go down too well in some of the other countries who had signed up to Breton Woods. French 
President Shaul later described this dynamic as a quote exorbitant privilege bestowed on the 
US by Breton Woods. The US was able to finance its own balance of payments deficits by issuing 
its own currency which other nations needed to hold as reserves. And yeah, when you put it like 
that, the word rigged does indeed come to mind. So, was the Bretton Woods system doomed by 
America’s refusal to play by the rules? Well, to some extent, yes. But that’s not the whole 
story. The system’s reliance on a national currency as the primary source of international 
liquidity was an inherent contradiction that would gradually prove fatal. The problem was first 
described by Belgian American economist Robert Triffin in the early 1960s. He argued that for the 
international monetary system based on a single goldbacked national reserve currency to have 
sufficient liquidity, the issuer of that currency would need to supply an everinccreasing amount 
of it to the rest of the world. As international trade flows increase and economies grow, so 
too does the demand for the reserve currency. This demand is typically met as a result of the 
issuer of the reserve currency running balance of payments deficits. But if net outflows continue 
indefinitely, the stock of the reserve currency held abroad will eventually exceed the issuing 
country’s gold holdings. This erodess confidence in the convertability of the reserve currency 
into gold, which becomes increasingly tenuous. If enough participants in the system take issue 
with the possibility that the issuer may not be able to redeem the supposedly gold pegged currency 
for gold, it could trigger a run on the currency and ultimately lead to the collapse of the 
system. Now, in theory, this could be avoided if the issuing country eliminates its deficits and 
maintains confidence in the system through fiscal discipline. But in reality, this is hardly a 
better option because it implies starving the rest of the world of liquidity, potentially leading to 
deflation and recession. This is why this dynamic came to be known as the Triffin dilemma, sometimes 
the Triffin paradox, because it’s an inescapable bind that makes the whole structure fundamentally 
unsustainable. In practice, this paradox played out pretty much exactly how Triffin called it. A 
key feature of the post-war global economy was the US running persistent balance of payments deficits 
that effectively flooded the rest of the world with dollars. With the exception of the countries 
at the sharp end of US military spending, these outflows were initially welcomed as they provided 
the international liquidity needed to finance expanding global trade and allow other countries 
to rebuild their reserves. But as the dollar liabilities held by foreign banks and private 
entities continued to pile up, it became hard to ignore the fact that the supply of dollars backed 
by gold was increasing while the gold needed to actually back them was not. The everinccreasing 
demand for dollars to fuel economic growth abroad could only be met if the US kept printing more 
dollars. But this made a mockery of the dollar’s gold peg. Now, under a system of free floating 
exchange rates, the increasingly shaky ground on which the dollar stood would likely have led to 
a swift depreciation in value. But the Bretonwood system prevented this due to the dollar’s unique 
role and the obligation of everyone else to maintain their own tight pegs to it. The investor 
and author Lynn Alden argues that Bretonwoods therefore led to a persistently overvalued dollar, 
making American exports more expensive and imports cheaper. This in turn tended to worsen the US’s 
trade deficit, further increasing the supply of dollars abroad and therefore making the triffin 
dilemma a self-reinforcing mechanism. For the US, Alden posits that the exorbitant privilege of 
issuing the world’s reserve currency came with a quote unmentioned exorbitant burden, namely the 
gradual erosion of its domestic manufacturing base and a growing net international investment 
position deficit. And although most of this erosion and investment position deficit 
post-date the end of Breton Woods, it’s nevertheless Bretton Woods that is responsible for 
making the dollar the world’s reserve currency. So perhaps you can see what a huge shadow this 
system continues to cast over the US and the world even long after it was terminated. And speaking 
of which, how did Bretton Woods end? Well, as you might have guessed, the world figured out 
that this system was full of holes and hopelessly unsustainable fairly quickly. Through the system 
of fixed exchange rates, Breton Woods enabled the US to export domestic inflation created by 
its rampant dollar printing. It was like a free money glitch for the US at the expense of everyone 
else. And unsurprisingly, everyone else got sick of this pretty fast. Countries including France, 
Germany, Japan, and Switzerland saw the writing on the wall and decided to swap their dollars for 
gold. France alone repatriated around 3,000 tons of it from vaults in the US between 1965 and 1971. 
This led to an awkward picture where there was an increasing amount of outstanding dollar claims 
against a decreasing amount of gold held in the US. Unsurprisingly, the rate of US gold depletion 
only accelerated over time as central banks and foreign governments raced to avoid becoming a 
bag holder of dollars pegged to non-existent gold. As the pretense of gold convertability wore 
thinner, the dollar was shorted relentlessly on the foreign exchange markets as speculators 
anticipated an inevitable devaluation of the dollar or a fundamental change to the system. 
For the US, devaluing the dollar was politically untenable and technically challenging and other 
countries were not in any hurry to revalue their currencies higher against the dollar either as 
this would make their exports less competitive. This rigidity prevented the system from adapting 
to the reality of divergent economic policies and performance among member nations, allowing 
imbalances to grow to unsustainable levels. By the summer of 1971, the game was clearly up. 
The artificially strong dollar had severely undermined the US’s international trade position, 
and the US was running out of gold amid a renewed run on the dollar. But this didn’t make it any 
less shocking when on the 15th of August 1971, President Richard Nixon abruptly announced on TV 
that Breton Woods was cancelled. To be precise, he announced a series of measures that he said 
were to quote stabilize the dollar, including a not so temporary end to gold convertability. 
Now, Nixon hadn’t consulted anyone but a small secret meeting of economists and advisers from 
the White House Treasury and Federal Reserve just two days earlier. There was much debate about 
what Nixon should do, but he ultimately went with Treasury Secretary John Conny’s suggestion to 
just can the whole thing. And yes, that’s the same John Connelly of JFK assassination 
motorcade fame. Anyway, later that year, Connelly told an astonished meeting of the G10 
nations that quote, “The dollar is our currency, but your problem quite.” And that, folks, is how 
fiat currency was born. Leaving money with no backing but the issuers monopoly on violence. 
Within a few years of Nixon’s announcement, most countries called it quits on trying to 
back their currencies with anything else. They let the value of their currencies float 
freely leading to a terminal decline in their value over time. Thankfully, of course, we now 
have Bitcoin to offer at least some relief against the downon price action of fiat currency. And this 
has come with greater awareness about the problems of fiat currency, which is particularly salient 
in our era of quantitative easing or programmatic money printing and impending sovereign debt 
crises that are likely to just be inflated away. But then again, it’s probably best not to imagine 
too fondly the good old days when dollars were backed by gold and everything else was backed by 
dollars because, well, what a mess that all turned out to be. The more things change, the more they 
stay the same, eh? Anyway, I’ll leave it for today there folks. As always, thank you for watching and 
I’ll see you next time. This is Guy. Over and out.

Fiat money: it’s valuable just because the government says it is, but we all know they’re going to just print more and more of it until our savings turn to dust.

It’s not like the good old days, when money was backed by solid gold, in a monetary system that everyone could believe in… right? Well, about that. Today, we investigate the system that came before fiat, to find out how it worked, how it changed the world, and just how much better it was – or worse – it really was.

~~~~~

🛒 Get The Hottest Crypto Deals 👉 https://www.coinbureau.com/deals/
♣️ Join The Coin Bureau Club 👉 https://hub.coinbureau.com/
📲 Insider Info in our Socials 👉 https://www.coinbureau.com/socials/
👕 Our Merch Store 👉 https://store.coinbureau.com/?utm_source=Youtube&utm_medium=No+CTA&utm_campaign=YT
🔥 TOP Crypto TIPS In our Newsletter 👉 https://www.coinbureau.com/newsletters/

~~~~~

🔥OUR BRAND PARTNERS🔥

📈Join Toobit for 100K USDT Bonus and 50% Lifetime Fee Discount 👉 https://coinbureau.com/deals/trading/toobit-cb/
🔒Get Your Ledger Wallet, Plus $10 of free BTC 👉 https://go.coinbureau.com/ledger.main
🔒Ledger Flex Solana Edition with $20 of SOL 👉https://go.coinbureau.com/LedgerFlex.SolanaEdition
🔒 Ledger Nano S Upgrade Offer – Get 20% off on new products 👉 https://go.coinbureau.com/Ledger/NanoSupgrade20

~~~~~

📺Essential Videos📺

Ethereum’s Michael Saylor? The Strange Story of Sharplink 👉https://youtu.be/o0grDr554bg
Incoming: $40 Trillion of Big Beautiful Debt 👉 https://youtu.be/MblA9L7dYNI?
Warren Buffet’s $347 Billion Doomsday Fund 👉 https://youtu.be/Ee83YmEqng0

~~~~~

– TIMESTAMPS –

0:00 Intro
0:46 Background
2:21 The Road to Bretton Woods
7:46 Bretton Woods: How the System Worked
13:32 Doomed to Fail?
17:48 Finale: It’s Our Currency, But Your Problem

~~~~~

📜 Disclaimer 📜

The information contained herein is for informational purposes only. Nothing herein shall be construed to be financial, legal or tax advice. The content of this video is solely the opinions of the speaker who is not a licensed financial advisor or registered investment advisor. Trading cryptocurrencies poses considerable risk of loss. The speaker does not guarantee any particular outcome.

#Macro #Fiat #gold